Banque de France Bulletin

Monetary policy measures during the first phase of the Covid-19 crisis

Published on 5 March 2021

Bulletin n°234, article 1. Covid-19 began to circulate in the euro area with a significant number of cases in late February and early March 2020. By 11 March, it had been declared a “global pandemic” by the World Health
Organization, and increasingly stringent restrictions were imposed to contain the public health emergency. Economic activity in many sectors was effectively suspended almost everywhere in the world. Measured economic output contracted at the fastest rate recorded since World War II. Between March and June, in response to the first stage of the crisis, the major central banks implemented monetary policy measures that shared many common features. Together, and combined with extraordinary government emergency responses, they have cushioned the economic crisis by short circuiting amplification mechanisms. This article does not cover the policy response to the more recent “second wave” of infections, after summer 2020.

Image Stylised flow chart of monetary policy intervention Description The graph introduces stylised flow chart of monetary policy intervention.  Source: Odendahl et al., 2020. Note: The chart shows the stylised flows of the ECB's monetary policy actions (colour-coded as in Chart 1). Orange arrows show the intended consequences of the policy interventions. Acronyms are explained in the gloassry. Key figures: -3.5%: global growth in 2020 projected by the IMF; -1%: lending rate to banks meeting a lending criteria under the ECB's Tardeted Long-Term Refinancing Operations. 1,350 billion euro: envelope of the ECB's Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme (PEEP was increased to EUR 1,850 billion on 10 December 2020.


Covid-19 is a highly virulent and deadly coronavirus that propagated rapidly in the euro area in its first wave from late February through to mid May 2020. Left to spread without government intervention, the pandemic would have overwhelmed health systems, resulting in even more people in need of medical attention.

The medical imperative to impose a partial or general lockdown of the population significantly reduced economic activity, increased the risk of business failures and led to a sharp rise in unemployment. In such circumstances, providing additional and temporary liquidity to businesses and households was essential. In parallel, an increase in volatility in financial markets caused by investors looking for liquidity required other targeted monetary policy interventions. Chart 1 presents a timeline of the actions taken by the four main G7 central banks: the European Central Bank (ECB), the Bank of Japan (BoJ), the US Federal Reserve (Fed), and the Bank of England (BoE). With the exception of the BoJ, which introduced a single package, the major central banks applied additional measures as estimates of the economic outlook worsened.

1 The unfolding economic crisis was different from the 2008 financial crisis…

The recession caused by Covid-19 will significantly exceed the one that followed the collapse of Lehman Brothers in 2008. The ultimate cost is still unclear but the global economy is forecasted to have contracted by –3.5 percent in 2020 by the IMF (IMF, 2021).

A key difference from the financial crisis of 2008 is that banks and other financial institutions were healthier when the emergency occurred and not the origin of the shock. Although there were initially very large falls in stock markets and increases in risk spreads, the financial system continued to function smoothly.

Instead, the primary focus of this crisis was and is on firms and households, particularly in countries where welfare safety nets and short time working schemes are less developed. The lockdown measures taken globally suspended economic activity in all service industries requiring physical proximity, severely constrained production and supply chains elsewhere and disrupted labour supply everywhere. The resulting loss of income and spending power by households and firms amplified the recession (Guerrieri et al., 2020; Gourinchas, 2020; ILO, 2020).

It is natural for firms and households under strain to start hoarding cash. Firms demand payment from creditors but delay making payments to suppliers. However, this harms the liquidity position of the supplier and so on down the line. (…)

[to read more, please download the article]