Eco Notepad

Is short-time work an effective job protection policy?

Published on 4 May 2018
Authors : Sandra Nevoux, Pierre Cahuc, Francis Kramarz

Post n°63. Short-time work schemes have been implemented in many OECD countries with a view to protecting jobs in companies experiencing temporary difficulties. While such schemes made it possible to save jobs during the Great Recession of 2008-2009, they may also have adverse effects on the economy. However, these effects would be minimised by sensible reforms.

Image Short-time work and growth
Chart 1. Short-time work and growth
Source: OECD.

Short-time work is an employment policy aimed at companies experiencing temporary difficulties. This mechanism sets out to protect jobs by temporarily reducing the number of hours worked by employees, while guaranteeing them for these unworked hours a compensation which is partly financed by the government.

Although this mechanism has existed in many OECD countries for a long time, it remained relatively unknown before the Great Recession of 2008-2009. During this period, several countries, notably Germany, introduced it or encouraged its use, which resulted in an increase in short-time work (see Chart 1). This coincided with a period of labour market resilience: the number of job losses was low with respect to the magnitude of the crisis. After the recession, some countries therefore decided to keep this scheme in place or even increase its generosity in order to support the economic recovery.

Short-time work is effective in times of crisis

Many studies highlight the positive effects of short-time work during crisis periods. This mechanism enables employees to keep their job and guarantees them a stable income. It allows companies to reduce the cost of labour and maintain their human capital. By avoiding redundancies, it improves the social climate and can contribute to bringing down unemployment insurance costs.

During the Great Recession of 2008-2009,  Cahuc, Kramarz and Nevoux (2018) showed that short-time work was an effective tool for saving jobs. According to Balleer, Gehrke, Lechthaler and Merkl (2016), 466,000 jobs were saved thanks to short-time work in Germany during this period.

Short-time work may also lead to a decrease in hours worked and output

However, several studies have shown adverse effects associated with short-time work, which emerged both during and after the crisis periods. In order to optimise labour costs, financially viable companies may place some employees on short-time work who would have been kept on full-time contracts in the absence of compensation. In this case, the mechanism results in a decrease in the number of hours worked with no positive impact on employment.

Short-time work may also be used by companies experiencing prolonged economic difficulties to subsidise jobs that would otherwise be lost and whose employees would have been, in the absence of this mechanism, dismissed and possibly hired by more productive firms.

In the end, by reducing hours worked and impeding the efficient reallocation of labour, these windfall and displacement effects lead to a decline in aggregate output.

The adverse effects of short-time work stem partly from its financing

According to these studies, the adverse effects of short-time work stem partly from the structure of this mechanism and notably from its method of financing. Indeed, short-time work is generally financed by taxes and/or unemployment insurance. The contributions of firms to short-time work therefore do not depend on how much they use this mechanism (except in the United States and to a lesser extent in Italy). This financing system thus results in a financial transfer from firms not using it to firms using it. This subsidy results in these schemes being overused and poorly distributed vis-à-vis the social optimum. In this respect, Cahuc and Nevoux (2017) show that the current short-time work mechanism in France is not suitable for insuring employees and firms against seasonal fluctuations in activity. Since this mechanism relies exclusively on public financing, the lack of contributions from firms benefiting from it leads to an overconsumption and too frequent use of short-time work schemes. For instance, the 2012-2013 reforms of short-time work generated a financial transfer to firms repeatedly using this mechanism and facing major seasonal fluctuations. Yet, these public subsidies, inevitably financed by other sectors and companies, lead to output losses at the macroeconomic level, in that they impede the reallocation of labour affected by seasonal fluctuations towards more productive sectors of activity.  The aggregate output loss associated with the current short-time work mechanism, vis-à-vis the social optimum, is estimated at 50% of the total short-time work subsidy granted to systematic users, or around EUR 40 million (see Chart 2).

Image  Total short-time work subsidy
Chart 2. Total short-time work subsidy (EUR million)
Sources: DADS (Insee), Sinapse (DGEFP) and Extranet (ASP).
Scope: Mainland France excluding Corsica; market sectors excluding agriculture ; firms using short-time work for reasons related to economic conditions.

Note: "5 years" represents systematic users, which use short-time work each year over the past 5 years; "3 to 4 years" represents repeated users, which use short-time work 3 to 4 years over the past 5 years; "1 to 2 years" represents occasional users, which use short-time work 1 to 2 years over the past 5 years .

Reforming the short-time work mechanism would make it possible to minimise its adverse effects

Several studies propose avenues for reforming the short-time work mechanism to improve its effectiveness. These reforms are similar to deductible or bonus-malus mechanisms in insurance. The government (the insurer) covers a fraction of the short-time work subsidies (insurance pay-out) in response to a negative shock, and the company (the insured) finances the rest (the deductible). In order to implement a bonus-malus system for short-time work, firms would have to contribute to the financing of the mechanism pro rata to their financial weight in it (insurance premium).

In this regard, Cahuc, Kramarz and Nevoux (2018) recommend establishing a threshold for triggering the short-time work mechanism below that of the current level of 35 hours. Indeed, this new threshold would minimise the windfall effects associated with short-time work, in that viable companies in the absence of this mechanism would have less incentive, in the event of a decrease in this threshold, to use it, whereas firms experiencing temporary difficulties would continue to use it.

The implementation of a bonus-malus system for short-time work is also presented as a solution for minimising its adverse effects. However, such a financing system would also reduce its attractiveness and would thus result in job losses. To avoid this, Cahuc and Nevoux (2018) propose implementing a bonus-malus system for both short-time work and unemployment insurance. The bonus-malus system for unemployment insurance would encourage companies experiencing temporary difficulties to use short-time work rather than dismissing employees, whereas the bonus-malus system for short-time work, by making companies bear the cost they represent in the mechanism, would prevent its overuse.